Shop - Adam Smith’s the Wealth of Nations

View All Photos
Karen McCreadie – ADAM SMITH’S THE WEALTH OF NATIONS : A Modern-Day Interpretation of An Economic Classic
Karen McCreadie – ADAM SMITH’S THE WEALTH OF NATIONS : A Modern-Day Interpretation of An Economic Classic
Karen McCreadie – ADAM SMITH’S THE WEALTH OF NATIONS : A Modern-Day Interpretation of An Economic Classic
Karen McCreadie – ADAM SMITH’S THE WEALTH OF NATIONS : A Modern-Day Interpretation of An Economic Classic
Karen McCreadie – ADAM SMITH’S THE WEALTH OF NATIONS : A Modern-Day Interpretation of An Economic Classic
Karen McCreadie – ADAM SMITH’S THE WEALTH OF NATIONS : A Modern-Day Interpretation of An Economic Classic
Karen McCreadie – ADAM SMITH’S THE WEALTH OF NATIONS : A Modern-Day Interpretation of An Economic Classic
Karen McCreadie – ADAM SMITH’S THE WEALTH OF NATIONS : A Modern-Day Interpretation of An Economic Classic
Karen McCreadie – ADAM SMITH’S THE WEALTH OF NATIONS : A Modern-Day Interpretation of An Economic Classic
Karen McCreadie – ADAM SMITH’S THE WEALTH OF NATIONS : A Modern-Day Interpretation of An Economic Classic

Adam Smith’s the Wealth of Nations

Karen Mccreadie
Brand-new, Paperback

RM15.00

To Illustrate The Timeless Nature of Smith’s Insights In 21st Century Context

Availability: In stock

Additional information

ISBN 9789674151157
Publisher MPH Group Publishing
Publication Date 6/12/2009
Pages 118
Weight N/A
Dimension N/A
  • Detail Description
  • Reviews (0)

Description

What was the most important document published in 1776?

Most Americans would probably say The Declaration of Independence. But many would argue that Adam Smith’s “The Wealth of Nations” had a bigger and more global impact.

Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations was the first comprehensive treatment of political economy.

Published in 1776, The Wealth of Nations was originally released for a very specific audience, the British Parliament, setting clearly defined arguments for peace and co-operation with the troublesome colonials across the Atlantic.

Today it is considered one of the most influential books ever written.

Here, Smith’s text is interpreted for the modern day world of finance, business and economics.

KEY TAKEAWAYS :
① The central thesis of Smith’s “The Wealth of Nations” is that our individual need to fulfill self-interest results in societal benefit, in what is known as his “invisible hand”.

② This, combined with the division of labor in an economy, results in a web of mutual interdepencies that promotes stability and prosperity through the market mechanism.

③ Smith rejects government interference in market activities, and instead states governments should serve just 3 functions: protect national borders; enforce civil law; and engage in public works (e.g. education).

The core of Smith’s thesis was that humans’ natural tendency toward self-interest (or in modern terms, looking out for yourself) results in prosperity.

Smith argued that by giving everyone freedom to produce and exchange goods as they pleased (free trade) and opening the markets up to domestic and foreign competition, people’s natural self-interest would promote greater prosperity than with stringent government regulations.

Smith believed humans ultimately promote public interest through their everyday economic choices.

“He (or she) generally, indeed, neither intends to promote the public interest nor knows how much he is promoting it. By preferring the support of domestic to that of foreign industry, he intends only his own security and by directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention,” he said in “An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.”

This free-market force became known as the invisible hand, but it needed support to bring about its magic.

In particular it was the market that emerged from an increasing division of labor, both within production processes and throughout society that created a series of mutual interdepencies, promoting social welfare through individual profit motives.

In other words, once you specialize as a baker and produce only bread, you now must rely on somebody else for your clothes, somebody else for your meat, and yet somebody else for your beer.

Meanwhile the people that specialize in clothes now must rely on you for their bread, and so on.

Adam Smith is generally regarded as the father of modern economics.

The Invisible Hand :

– The automatic pricing and distribution mechanisms in the economy—which Adam Smith called an “invisible hand”—interact directly and indirectly with centralized, top-down planning authorities. However, there are some meaningful conceptual fallacies in an argument that is framed as the invisible hand versus the government.

– The invisible hand is not actually a distinguishable entity. Instead, it is the sum of many phenomena that occur when consumers and producers engage in commerce. Smith’s insight into the idea of the invisible hand was one of the most important in the history of economics. It remains one of the chief justifications for free-market ideologies.

– The invisible hand theorem (at least in its modern interpretations) suggests that the means of production and distribution should be privately owned and that if trade occurs unfettered by regulation, in turn, society will flourish organically. These arguments are naturally competitive with the concept and function of government.

– The government is not serendipitous—it is prescriptive and intentional. Politicians, regulators, and those who exercise legal force (such as the courts, police, and military) pursue defined goals through coercion.

However, in contrast, macroeconomic forces—supply and demand, buying and selling, profit and loss occur voluntarily until government policy inhibits or overrides them.

In this sense, it is more accurate to suggest that government affects the invisible hand, not the other way around.

However, it is the absence of market mechanisms that frustrates government planning.

Some economists refer to this as the economic calculation problem. When people and businesses individually make decisions based on their willingness to pay money for a good or service, that information is captured dynamically in the price mechanism.

This, in turn, allocates resources automatically toward the most valued ends.

When governments interfere with this process, unwanted shortages and surpluses tend to occur.

Consider the massive gas shortages in the United States during the 1970s. The then newly formed Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) cut production to raise oil prices.

The Nixon and Ford administrations responded by introducing price controls to limit the cost of gasoline to American consumers.

The goal was to make cheap gas available to the public.

Instead, gas stations had no incentive to stay open for more than a few hours.

Oil companies had no incentive to increase production domestically. Consumers had every incentive to buy more gasoline than they needed.

Large-scale shortages and gas lines resulted. Those gas lines disappeared almost immediately after controls were eliminated and prices were allowed to rise.

While it is tempting to say the invisible hand limits government, that wouldn’t necessarily be correct.

Rather, the forces that guide voluntary economic activity toward large societal benefit are the same forces that limit the effectiveness of government intervention.

The Elements of Prosperity :
Boiling the principles Smith expressed regarding the invisible hand and other concepts down to essentials, Smith believed a nation needed the following three elements to bring about universal prosperity.

1. Enlightened Self-Interest

Smith wanted people to practice thrift, hard work, and enlightened self-interest. He thought the practice of enlightened self-interest was natural for the majority of people.

In his famous example, a butcher does not supply meat based on good-hearted intentions, but because he profits by selling meat. If the meat he sells is poor, he will not have repeat customers and, thus, no profit.

Therefore, it’s in the butcher’s interest to sell good meat at a price that customers are willing to pay, so that both parties benefit in every transaction. Smith believed the ability to think long-term would curb most businesses from abusing customers. When that wasn’t enough, he looked to the government to enforce laws.

Extending upon self-interest in trade, Smith saw thrift and savings as important virtues, especially when savings were used to invest.

Through investment, the industry would have the capital to buy more labor-saving machinery and encourage innovation.

This technological leap forward would increase returns on invested capital and raise the overall standard of living.

2. Limited Government

Smith saw the responsibilities of the government as being limited to the defense of the nation, universal education, public works (infrastructure such as roads and bridges), the enforcement of legal rights (property rights and contracts), and the punishment of crime.

The government would step in when people acted on their short-term interests and would make and enforce laws against robbery, fraud, and other similar crimes.

He cautioned against larger, bureaucratic governments, writing, “there is no art which one government sooner learns of another, than that of draining money from the pockets of the people.”

His focus on universal education was to counteract the negative and dulling effects of the division of labor that was a necessary part of industrialization.

3. Solid Currency and Free-Market Economy

The third element Smith proposed was a solid currency twinned with free-market principles. By backing currency with hard metals, Smith hoped to curtail the government’s ability to depreciate currency by circulating more of it to pay for wars or other wasteful expenditures.

With hard currency acting as a check on spending, Smith wanted the government to follow free-market principles by keeping taxes low and allowing free trade across borders by eliminating tariffs.

He pointed out that tariffs and other taxes only succeeded in making life more expensive for the people while also stifling industry and trade abroad.

Karen McCreadie’s interpretation is not a substitute for the original; its purpose is simply to illustrate the timeless nature of Smith’s insights by bringing them to life through 21st century examples.

Reviews

There are no reviews yet.


Be the first to review “Adam Smith’s the Wealth of Nations”

Something1
You've just added this product to the cart: